Chapter 71

306De Groot, p. 455.↑307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑308Lenz, p. 59.↑309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑311Martius, p. 63.↑312See above,p. 269.↑313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑323Robidé, p. 227.↑324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑327Cooper, p. 183.↑328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑329Rousselet, p. 223.↑330See above, p. 287.↑331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑332Ibid., p. 268.↑333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑308Lenz, p. 59.↑309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑311Martius, p. 63.↑312See above,p. 269.↑313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑323Robidé, p. 227.↑324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑327Cooper, p. 183.↑328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑329Rousselet, p. 223.↑330See above, p. 287.↑331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑332Ibid., p. 268.↑333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑308Lenz, p. 59.↑309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑311Martius, p. 63.↑312See above,p. 269.↑313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑323Robidé, p. 227.↑324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑327Cooper, p. 183.↑328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑329Rousselet, p. 223.↑330See above, p. 287.↑331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑332Ibid., p. 268.↑333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑308Lenz, p. 59.↑309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑311Martius, p. 63.↑312See above,p. 269.↑313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑323Robidé, p. 227.↑324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑327Cooper, p. 183.↑328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑329Rousselet, p. 223.↑330See above, p. 287.↑331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑332Ibid., p. 268.↑333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑308Lenz, p. 59.↑309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑311Martius, p. 63.↑312See above,p. 269.↑313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑323Robidé, p. 227.↑324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑327Cooper, p. 183.↑328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑329Rousselet, p. 223.↑330See above, p. 287.↑331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑332Ibid., p. 268.↑333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑

306De Groot, p. 455.↑

307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑

307Blumentritt,Conquista, p. 53.↑

308Lenz, p. 59.↑

308Lenz, p. 59.↑

309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑

309Compiègne, Okanda, pp. 194, 195.↑

310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑

310Torday and Joyce, Ba-Mbala, p. 411.↑

311Martius, p. 63.↑

311Martius, p. 63.↑

312See above,p. 269.↑

312See above,p. 269.↑

313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑

313Leroy-Beaulieu, p. 80. See also Malthus (Bettany’s edition, pp. 423, 424): “In the feudal times, the landlords could in no other way spend their incomes than by maintaining a great number of idle followers.”↑

314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑

314Coquilhat, pp. 365, 265.↑

315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑

315Finsch,Die Goldküste, pp. 359, 360.↑

316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑

316Among hunting agriculturists we have found 34 positive and 43 negative cases; among agriculturists of the higher stages 136 positive and 52 negative cases.↑

317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑

317Morgan, Anc. Soc., p. 136.↑

318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑

318See Salvioli’s article on the struggles between pastoral and agricultural peoples.↑

319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑

319See above, p. 295, and Grosse, p. 134.↑

320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑

320Martius, pp. 123, 131, 131 note, 154 note, 531–533, 772.↑

321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑

321Robidé, pp. 345 sqq.↑

322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑

322Ibid., pp. 53, 218, 221, 288, 289, 232, 255, 317. See also “Nieuw Guinea”, pp. 186–192.↑

323Robidé, p. 227.↑

323Robidé, p. 227.↑

324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑

324Ibid., pp. 277, 242.↑

325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑

325Ottow and Geissler, pp. 152, 153.↑

326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑

326See Blumentritt,Conquista.↑

327Cooper, p. 183.↑

327Cooper, p. 183.↑

328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑

328Colquhoun, p. 70.↑

329Rousselet, p. 223.↑

329Rousselet, p. 223.↑

330See above, p. 287.↑

330See above, p. 287.↑

331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑

331Ingram, pp. 19, 38.↑

332Ibid., p. 268.↑

332Ibid., p. 268.↑

333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑

333Ibid., 224, 225, 230–233. On the African slave-trade, see also Ratzel,Anthropogeographie,II (1891), pp. 386, 387.↑

334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑

334Polack, I,pp. 78, 79.↑

335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑

335In ancient Wales “the price of a slave was one pound, but of one brought across the sea, a pound and a half. The slave who was brought from a distance was much less likely to escape, or even to attempt it, and was therefore a more valuable property; this principle still holds good among slave-owners.” Cunningham, English Industry, I,p. 117 note 6.↑


Back to IndexNext