CHAPTER III

NOTES:[35]Young'sTravels in Francewas republished in 1892, with a preface and short life by Miss Betham Edwards. She has since (1898) published his autobiography. See also the autobiographical sketch in theAnnals of Agriculture, xv. 152-97. Young'sFarmer's Lettersfirst appeared in 1767; hisToursin the Southern, Northern, and Eastern Counties in 1768, 1770, and 1771; hisTour in Irelandin 1780; and hisTravels in Francein 1792. A useful bibliography, containing a list of his many publications, is appended to the edition of theTour in Irelandedited by Mr. A. W. Hutton in 1892.[36]Annals, xv. 166.[37]Travels in France(1892), p. 184n.[38]Travels in France, p. 54.[39]Ibid.p. 109.[40]Ibid.p. 61.[41]Ibid.p. 70.[42]Ibid.p. 279.[43]Travels in France, p. 125.[44]Ibid.p. 131.[45]Ibid.pp. 198, 298.[46]Ibid.pp. 55, 193, 199, 237.[47]Ibid.p. 43.[48]Travels in France, pp. 291-92.[49]Ibid.p. 132.[50]Ibid.p. 66.[51]Ibid.p. 131.[52]e.g.Southern Tour, p. 103;Northern Tour, p. 180 (York Cathedral).[53]Northern Tour, iv. 344, 377.[54]Irish Tour, ii. 114.[55]Southern Tour, p. 326.[56]Southern Tour, p. 22.[57]Annals, i. 380.[58]Ibid.vol, x.[59]Ibid.iv. 17.[60]Southern Tour, p. 262;Northern Tour, ii. 412.[61]Northern Tour, iv. 410, etc.[62]Irish Tour, ii. 118-19.[63]Memoirs of Sir John Sinclair, by his son. 2 vols., 1837.[64]Memoirs, i. 338.[65]A New Statistical Account, replacing this, appeared in twenty-four volumes from 1834 to 1844.[66]He was president for the first five years, and again, from 1806 till 1813. For an account of this, see Sir Ernest Clarke'sHistory of the Board of Agriculture, 1898.[67]Northern Tour, i. 222-32.[68]Northern Tour, ii. 186.[69]Southern Tour, p. 20.[70]Northern Tour, iii. 365.[71]Arthur Young had a low opinion of Sinclair, whom he took to be a pushing and consequential busybody, more anxious to make a noise than to be useful. See Young'sAutobiography(1898), pp. 243, 315, 437. Sir Ernest Clarke points out the injury done by Sinclair's hasty and blundering extravagance; but also shows that the board did great service in stimulating agricultural improvement.[72]Scott'sLetters, i. 202.[73]Essay on 'Turgot.' See, in Daire's Collection of theÉconomistes, the arguments of Quesnay (p. 81), Dupont de Nemours (p. 360), and Mercier de la Rivière in favour of a legal (as distinguished from an 'arbitrary') despotism.

[35]Young'sTravels in Francewas republished in 1892, with a preface and short life by Miss Betham Edwards. She has since (1898) published his autobiography. See also the autobiographical sketch in theAnnals of Agriculture, xv. 152-97. Young'sFarmer's Lettersfirst appeared in 1767; hisToursin the Southern, Northern, and Eastern Counties in 1768, 1770, and 1771; hisTour in Irelandin 1780; and hisTravels in Francein 1792. A useful bibliography, containing a list of his many publications, is appended to the edition of theTour in Irelandedited by Mr. A. W. Hutton in 1892.

[35]Young'sTravels in Francewas republished in 1892, with a preface and short life by Miss Betham Edwards. She has since (1898) published his autobiography. See also the autobiographical sketch in theAnnals of Agriculture, xv. 152-97. Young'sFarmer's Lettersfirst appeared in 1767; hisToursin the Southern, Northern, and Eastern Counties in 1768, 1770, and 1771; hisTour in Irelandin 1780; and hisTravels in Francein 1792. A useful bibliography, containing a list of his many publications, is appended to the edition of theTour in Irelandedited by Mr. A. W. Hutton in 1892.

[36]Annals, xv. 166.

[36]Annals, xv. 166.

[37]Travels in France(1892), p. 184n.

[37]Travels in France(1892), p. 184n.

[38]Travels in France, p. 54.

[38]Travels in France, p. 54.

[39]Ibid.p. 109.

[39]Ibid.p. 109.

[40]Ibid.p. 61.

[40]Ibid.p. 61.

[41]Ibid.p. 70.

[41]Ibid.p. 70.

[42]Ibid.p. 279.

[42]Ibid.p. 279.

[43]Travels in France, p. 125.

[43]Travels in France, p. 125.

[44]Ibid.p. 131.

[44]Ibid.p. 131.

[45]Ibid.pp. 198, 298.

[45]Ibid.pp. 198, 298.

[46]Ibid.pp. 55, 193, 199, 237.

[46]Ibid.pp. 55, 193, 199, 237.

[47]Ibid.p. 43.

[47]Ibid.p. 43.

[48]Travels in France, pp. 291-92.

[48]Travels in France, pp. 291-92.

[49]Ibid.p. 132.

[49]Ibid.p. 132.

[50]Ibid.p. 66.

[50]Ibid.p. 66.

[51]Ibid.p. 131.

[51]Ibid.p. 131.

[52]e.g.Southern Tour, p. 103;Northern Tour, p. 180 (York Cathedral).

[52]e.g.Southern Tour, p. 103;Northern Tour, p. 180 (York Cathedral).

[53]Northern Tour, iv. 344, 377.

[53]Northern Tour, iv. 344, 377.

[54]Irish Tour, ii. 114.

[54]Irish Tour, ii. 114.

[55]Southern Tour, p. 326.

[55]Southern Tour, p. 326.

[56]Southern Tour, p. 22.

[56]Southern Tour, p. 22.

[57]Annals, i. 380.

[57]Annals, i. 380.

[58]Ibid.vol, x.

[58]Ibid.vol, x.

[59]Ibid.iv. 17.

[59]Ibid.iv. 17.

[60]Southern Tour, p. 262;Northern Tour, ii. 412.

[60]Southern Tour, p. 262;Northern Tour, ii. 412.

[61]Northern Tour, iv. 410, etc.

[61]Northern Tour, iv. 410, etc.

[62]Irish Tour, ii. 118-19.

[62]Irish Tour, ii. 118-19.

[63]Memoirs of Sir John Sinclair, by his son. 2 vols., 1837.

[63]Memoirs of Sir John Sinclair, by his son. 2 vols., 1837.

[64]Memoirs, i. 338.

[64]Memoirs, i. 338.

[65]A New Statistical Account, replacing this, appeared in twenty-four volumes from 1834 to 1844.

[65]A New Statistical Account, replacing this, appeared in twenty-four volumes from 1834 to 1844.

[66]He was president for the first five years, and again, from 1806 till 1813. For an account of this, see Sir Ernest Clarke'sHistory of the Board of Agriculture, 1898.

[66]He was president for the first five years, and again, from 1806 till 1813. For an account of this, see Sir Ernest Clarke'sHistory of the Board of Agriculture, 1898.

[67]Northern Tour, i. 222-32.

[67]Northern Tour, i. 222-32.

[68]Northern Tour, ii. 186.

[68]Northern Tour, ii. 186.

[69]Southern Tour, p. 20.

[69]Southern Tour, p. 20.

[70]Northern Tour, iii. 365.

[70]Northern Tour, iii. 365.

[71]Arthur Young had a low opinion of Sinclair, whom he took to be a pushing and consequential busybody, more anxious to make a noise than to be useful. See Young'sAutobiography(1898), pp. 243, 315, 437. Sir Ernest Clarke points out the injury done by Sinclair's hasty and blundering extravagance; but also shows that the board did great service in stimulating agricultural improvement.

[71]Arthur Young had a low opinion of Sinclair, whom he took to be a pushing and consequential busybody, more anxious to make a noise than to be useful. See Young'sAutobiography(1898), pp. 243, 315, 437. Sir Ernest Clarke points out the injury done by Sinclair's hasty and blundering extravagance; but also shows that the board did great service in stimulating agricultural improvement.

[72]Scott'sLetters, i. 202.

[72]Scott'sLetters, i. 202.

[73]Essay on 'Turgot.' See, in Daire's Collection of theÉconomistes, the arguments of Quesnay (p. 81), Dupont de Nemours (p. 360), and Mercier de la Rivière in favour of a legal (as distinguished from an 'arbitrary') despotism.

[73]Essay on 'Turgot.' See, in Daire's Collection of theÉconomistes, the arguments of Quesnay (p. 81), Dupont de Nemours (p. 360), and Mercier de la Rivière in favour of a legal (as distinguished from an 'arbitrary') despotism.

I.PAUPERISM

Perhaps the gravest of all the problems which were to occupy the coming generation was the problem of pauperism. The view taken by the Utilitarians was highly characteristic and important. I will try to indicate the general position of intelligent observers at the end of the century by referring to the remarkable book of Sir Frederick Morton Eden. Its purport is explained by the title: 'The State of the Poor; or, an History of the Labouring Classes of England from the Norman Conquest to the present period; in which are particularly considered their domestic economy, with respect to diet, dress, fuel, and habitation; and the various plans which have from time to time been proposed and adopted for the relief of the poor' (3 vols. 4to, 1797). Eden[74](1766-1809) was a man of good family and nephew of the first Lord Auckland, who negotiated Pitt's commercial treaty. He graduated as B.A. from Christ Church, Oxford, in 1787; married in 1792, and at his death (14th Nov. 1809) was chairman of the Globe Insurance Company. He wrotevarious pamphlets upon economical topics; contributed letters signed 'Philanglus' to Cobbett'sPorcupine, the anti-jacobin paper of the day; and is described by Bentham[75]as a 'declared disciple' and a 'highly valued friend.' He may be reckoned, therefore, as a Utilitarian, though politically he was a Conservative. He seems to have been a man of literary tastes as well as a man of business, and his book is a clear and able statement of the points at issue.

Eden's attention had been drawn to the subject by the distress which followed the outbreak of the revolutionary war. He employed an agent who travelled through the country for a year with a set of queries drawn up after the model of those prepared by Sinclair for hisStatistical Account of Scotland. He thus anticipated the remarkable investigation made in our own time by Mr. Charles Booth. Eden made personal inquiries and studied the literature of the subject. He had a precursor in Richard Burn (1709-1785), whoseHistory of the Poor-lawsappeared in 1764, and a competitor in John Ruggles, whoseHistory of the Poorfirst appeared in Arthur Young'sAnnals, and was published as a book in 1793 (second edition, 1797). Eden's work eclipsed Ruggles's. It has a permanent value as a collection of facts; and was a sign of the growing sense of the importance of accurate statistical research. The historian of the social condition of the people should be grateful to one who broke ground at a time when the difficulty of obtaining a sound base for social inquiries began to make itself generally felt. The value of the book for historical purposes lies beyond my sphere. His first volume, I may say, gives a history oflegislation from the earliest period; and contains also a valuable account of the voluminous literature which had grown up during the two preceding centuries. The other two summarise the reports which he had received. I will only say enough to indicate certain critical points. Eden's book unfortunately was to mark, not a solution of the difficulty but, the emergence of a series of problems which were to increase in complexity and ominous significance through the next generation.

The general history of the poor-law is sufficiently familiar.[76]The mediæval statutes take us to a period at which the labourer was still regarded as a serf; and a man who had left his village was treated like a fugitive slave. A long series of statutes regulated the treatment of the 'vagabond.' The vagabond, however, had become differentiated from the pauper. The decay of the ancient order of society and its corresponding institutions had led to a new set of problems; and the famous statute of Elizabeth (1601) had laid down the main lines of the system which is still in operation.

When the labourer was regarded as in a servile condition, he might be supported from the motives which lead an owner to support his slaves, or by the charitable energies organised by ecclesiastical institutions. He had now ceased to be a serf, and the institutions which helped the poor man or maintained the beggar were wrecked. The Elizabethan statute gave him, therefore, a legal claim to be supported, and, on the other hand, directed that he should be made to work for his living. The assumption is still that every man is a member of alittle social circle. He belongs to his parish, and it is his fellow-parishioners who are bound to support him. So long as this corresponded to facts, the system could work satisfactorily. With the spread of commerce, and the growth of a less settled population, difficulties necessarily arose. The pauper and the vagabond represent a kind of social extravasation; the 'masterless man' who has strayed from his legitimate place or has become a superfluity in his own circle. The vagabond could be flogged, sent to prison, or if necessary hanged, but it was more difficult to settle what to do with a man who was not a criminal, but simply a product in excess of demand. All manner of solutions had been suggested by philanthropists and partly adopted by the legislature. One point which especially concerns us is the awkwardness or absence of an appropriate administrative machinery.

The parish, the unit on which the pauper had claims, meant the persons upon whom the poor-rate was assessed. These were mainly farmers and small tradesmen who formed the rather vague body called the vestry. 'Overseers' were appointed by the ratepayers themselves; they were not paid, and the disagreeable office was taken in turn for short periods. The most obvious motive with the average ratepayer was of course to keep down the rates and to get the burthen of the poor as much as possible out of his own parish. Each parish had at least an interest in economy. But the economical interest also produced flagrant evils.

In the first place, there was the war between parishes. The law of settlement—which was to decide to what parish a pauper belonged—originated in an act of 1662.Eden observes that the short clause in this short act had brought more profit to the lawyers than 'any other point in the English jurisprudence.'[77]It is said that the expense of such a litigation before the act of 1834 averaged from £300,000 to £350,000 a year.[78]Each parish naturally endeavoured to shift the burthen upon its neighbours; and was protected by laws which enabled it to resist the immigration of labourers or actually to expel them when likely to become chargeable. This law is denounced by Adam Smith[79]as a 'violation of natural liberty and justice.' It was often harder, he declared, for a poor man to cross the artificial boundaries of his parish than to cross a mountain ridge or an arm of the sea. There was, he declared, hardly a poor man in England over forty who had not been at some time 'cruelly oppressed' by the working of this law. Eden thinks that Smith had exaggerated the evil: but a law which operated by preventing a free circulation of labour, and made it hard for a poor man to seek the best price for his only saleable commodity, was, so far, opposed to the fundamental principles common to Smith and Eden. The law, too, might be used oppressively by the niggardly and narrow-minded. The overseer, as Burn complained,[80]was often a petty tyrant: his aim was to depopulate his parish; to prevent the poor from obtaining a settlement; to make the workhouse a terror by placing it under the management of a bully; and by allkinds of chicanery to keep down the rates at whatever cost to the comfort and morality of the poor. This explains the view taken by Arthur Young, and generally accepted at the period, that the poor-law meant depopulation. Workhouses had been started in the seventeenth century[81]with the amiable intention of providing the industrious poor with work. Children might be trained to industry and the pauper might be made self-supporting. Workhouses were expected that is, to provide not only work but wages. Defoe, in hisGiving Alms no Charity, pointed out the obvious objections to the workhouse considered as an institution capable of competing with the ordinary industries. Workhouses, in fact, soon ceased to be profitable. Their value, however, in supplying a test for destitution was recognised; and by an act of 1722, parishes were allowed to set up workhouses, separately or in combination, and to strike off the lists of the poor those who refused to enter them. This was the germ of the later 'workhouse test.'[82]When grievances arose, the invariable plan, as Nicholls observes,[83]was to increase the power of the justices. Their discretion was regarded 'as a certain cure for every shortcoming of the law and every evil arising out of it.' The great report of 1834 traces this tendency[84]to a clause in an act passed in the reign of WilliamIII., which was intended to allow the justices to check the extravagance of parish officers. They were empowered to strike off persons improperly relieved. This incidental regulation, widened by subsequent interpretations,allowed the magistrates to order relief, and thereby introduced an incredible amount of demoralisation.

The course was natural enough, and indeed apparently inevitable. The justices of the peace represented the only authority which could be called in to regulate abuses arising from the incapacity and narrow local interests of the multitudinous vestries. The schemes of improvement generally involved some plan for a larger area. If a hundred or a county were taken for the unit, the devices which depopulated a parish would no longer be applicable.[85]The only scheme actually carried was embodied in 'Gilbert's act' (1782), obtained by Thomas Gilbert (1720-1798), an agent of the duke of Bridgewater, and an active advocate of poor-law reform in the House of Commons. This scheme was intended as a temporary expedient during the distress caused by the American War; and a larger and more permanent scheme which it was to introduce failed to become law. It enabled parishes to combine if they chose to provide common workhouses, and to appoint 'guardians.' The justices, as usual, received more powers in order to suppress the harsh dealing of the old parochial authorities. The guardians, it was assumed, could always find 'work,' and they were to relieve the able-bodied without applying the workhouse test. The act, readily adopted, thus became a landmark in the growth of laxity.[86]

At the end of the century a rapid development of pauperism had taken place. The expense, as Eden had to complain, had doubled in twenty years. This took place simultaneously with the great development of manufactures. It is not perhaps surprising, though it may be melancholy, that increase of wealth shall be accompanied by increase of pauperism. Where there are many rich men, there will be a better field for thieves and beggars. A life of dependence becomes easier though it need not necessarily be adopted. Whatever may have been the relation of the two phenomena, the social revolution made the old social arrangements more inadequate. Great aggregations of workmen were formed in towns, which were still only villages in a legal sense. Fluctuations of trade, due to war or speculation, brought distress to the improvident; and the old assumption that every man had a proper place in a small circle, where his neighbours knew all about him, was further than ever from being verified. One painful result was already beginning to show itself. Neglected children in great towns had already excited compassion. Thomas Coram (1668?-1751) had been shocked by the sight of dying children exposed in the streets of London, and succeeded in establishing the Foundling Hospital (founded in 1742). In 1762, Jonas Hanway (1712-1786) obtained a law for boarding out children born within the bills of mortality. The demand for children's labour, produced by the factories, seemed naturally enough to offer a better chance for extending such charities. Unfortunately among the people who took advantage of it were parish officials, eager to get children off their hands, and manufacturers concerned only tomake money out of childish labour. Hence arose the shameful system for which remedies (as I shall have to notice) had to be sought in a later generation.

Meanwhile the outbreak of the revolutionary war had made the question urgent. When Manchester trade suffered, as Eden tells us in his reports, many workmen enlisted in the army, and left their children to be supported by the parish. Bad seasons followed in 1794 and 1795, and there was great distress in the agricultural districts. The governing classes became alarmed. In December 1795 Whitbread introduced a bill providing that the justices of the peace should fix a minimum rate of wages. Upon a motion for the second reading, Pitt made the famous speech (12th December) including the often-quoted statement that when a man had a family, relief should be 'a matter of right and honour, instead of a ground of opprobrium and contempt.'[87]Pitt had in the same speech shown his reading of Adam Smith by dwelling upon the general objections to state interference with wages, and had argued that more was to be gained by removing the restrictions upon the free movement of labour. He undertook to produce a comprehensive measure; and an elaborate bill of 130 clauses was prepared in 1796.[88]The rates were to be used to supplement inadequate wages; 'schools of industry' were to be formed for the support of superabundant children; loans might be made to the poor for the purchase of a cow;[89]and the possession of property was not to disqualify forthe receiving relief. In short, the bill seems to have been a model of misapplied benevolence. The details were keenly criticised by Bentham, and the bill never came to the birth. Other topics were pressing enough at this time to account for the failure of a measure so vast in its scope. Meanwhile something had to be done. On 6th May 1795 the Berkshire magistrates had passed certain resolutions called from their place of meeting, the 'Speenhamland Act of Parliament.' They provided that the rate of wages of a labourer should be increased in proportion to the price of corn and to the number of his family—a rule which, as Eden observes, tended to discourage economy of food in times of scarcity. They also sanctioned the disastrous principle of paying part of the wages out of rates. An act passed in 1796 repealed the old restrictions upon out-door relief; and thus, during the hard times that were to follow, the poor-laws were adapted to produce the state of things in which, as Cobbett says (in 1821) 'every labourer who has children is now regularly and constantly a pauper.'[90]The result represents a curious compromise. The landowners, whether from benevolence or fear of revolution, desired to meet the terrible distress of the times. Unfortunately their spasmodic interference was guided by no fixed principles, and acted upon a class of institutions not organised upon any definite system. The general effect seems to have been that the ratepayers, no longer allowed to 'depopulate,' sought to turn the compulsory stream of charity partly into their own pockets. If they were forced to support paupers, they could contrive to save the payment of wages. They could use the labour of therate-supported pauper instead of employing independent workmen. The evils thus produced led before long to most important discussions.[91]The ordinary view of the poor-law was inverted. The prominent evil was the reckless increase of a degraded population instead of the restriction of population. Eden's own view is sufficiently indicative of the light in which the facts showed themselves to intelligent economists. As a disciple of Adam Smith, he accepts the rather vague doctrine of his master about the 'balance' between labour and capital. If labour exceeds capital, he says, the labourer must starve 'in spite of all political regulations.'[92]He therefore looks with disfavour upon the whole poor-law system. It is too deeply rooted to be abolished, but he thinks that the amount to be raised should not be permitted to exceed the sum levied on an average of previous years. The only certain result of Pitt's measure would be a vast expenditure upon a doubtful experiment: and one main purpose of his publication was to point out the objections to the plan. He desires what seemed at that time to be almost hopeless, a national system of education; but his main doctrine is the wisdom of reliance upon individual effort. The truth of the maxim 'pas trop gouverner,' he says,[93]has never been better illustrated than by the contrast between friendly societies and the poor-laws. Friendly societies had been known, though they were still on a humble scale, from the beginning of the century, and had tended to diminish pauperism in spite of the poor-laws. Edengives many accounts of them. They seem to have suggested a scheme proposed by the worthy Francis Maseres[94](1731-1824) in 1772 for the establishment of life annuities. A bill to give effect to this scheme passed the House of Commons in 1773 with the support of Burke and Savile, but was thrown out in the House of Lords. In 1786 John Acland (died 1796), a Devonshire clergyman and justice of the peace, proposed a scheme for uniting the whole nation into a kind of friendly society for the support of the poor when out of work and in old age. It was criticised by John Howlett (1731-1804), a clergyman who wrote much upon the poor-laws. He attributes the growth of pauperism to the rise of prices, and calculates that out of an increased expenditure of £700,000, £219,000 had been raised by the rich, and the remainder 'squeezed out of the flesh, blood, and bones of the poor,' An act for establishing Acland's crude scheme failed next year in parliament.[95]The merit of the societies, according to Eden, was their tendency to stimulate self-help; and how to preserve that merit, while making them compulsory, was a difficult problem. I have said enough to mark a critical and characteristic change of opinion. One source of evil pointed out by contemporaries had been the absence of any central power which could regulate and systematise the action of the petty local bodies. The very possibilityof such organisation, however, seems to have been simply inconceivable. When the local bodies became lavish instead of over-frugal, the one remedy suggested was to abolish the system altogether.

NOTES:[74]SeeDictionary of National Biography.[75]Works, i. 255.[76]See Sir G. Nicholls'sHistory of the Poor-law, 1854. A new edition, with life by H. G. Willink, appeared in 1898.[77]History, i. 175.[78]M'Culloch's note toWealth of Nations, p. 65. M'Culloch in his appendix makes some sensible remarks upon the absence of any properly constituted parochial 'tribunal.'[79]Wealth of Nations, bk. i. ch. x.[80]See passage quoted in Eden'sHistory, i. 347.[81]Thomas Firmin (1632-1677), a philanthropist, whose Socinianism did not exclude him from the friendship of such liberal bishops as Tillotson and Fowler, started a workhouse in 1676.[82]Nicholls (1898), ii. 14.[83]Ibid.(1898), ii. 123.[84]Report, p. 67.[85]William Hay, for example, carried resolutions in the House of Commons in 1735, but failed to carry a bill which had this object. See Eden'sHistory, i. 396. Cooper in 1763 proposed to make the hundred the unit.—Nicholls'sHistory, i. 58. Fielding proposes a similar change in London. Dean Tucker speaks of the evil of the limited area in hisManifold Causes of the Increase of the Poor(1760).[86]Nicholls, ii. 88.[87]Parl. Hist.xxxii. 710.[88]A full abstract is given in EdensHistory, iii. ccclxiii. etc.[89]Bentham observes (Works, viii. 448) that the cow will require the three acres to keep it.[90]Cobbett'sPolitical Works, vi. 64[91]I need only note here that the first edition of Malthus'sEssayappeared in 1798, the year after Eden's publication.[92]Eden'sHistory, i. 583.[93]Ibid.i. 587.[94]Maseres, an excellent Whig, a good mathematician, and a respected lawyer, is perhaps best known at present from his portrait in Charles Lamb'sOld Benchers.[95]It maybe noticed as an anticipation of modern schemes that in 1792 Paine proposed a system of 'old age pensions,' for which the necessary funds were to be easily obtained when universal peace had abolished all military charges. SeeState Trials, xxv. 175.

[74]SeeDictionary of National Biography.

[74]SeeDictionary of National Biography.

[75]Works, i. 255.

[75]Works, i. 255.

[76]See Sir G. Nicholls'sHistory of the Poor-law, 1854. A new edition, with life by H. G. Willink, appeared in 1898.

[76]See Sir G. Nicholls'sHistory of the Poor-law, 1854. A new edition, with life by H. G. Willink, appeared in 1898.

[77]History, i. 175.

[77]History, i. 175.

[78]M'Culloch's note toWealth of Nations, p. 65. M'Culloch in his appendix makes some sensible remarks upon the absence of any properly constituted parochial 'tribunal.'

[78]M'Culloch's note toWealth of Nations, p. 65. M'Culloch in his appendix makes some sensible remarks upon the absence of any properly constituted parochial 'tribunal.'

[79]Wealth of Nations, bk. i. ch. x.

[79]Wealth of Nations, bk. i. ch. x.

[80]See passage quoted in Eden'sHistory, i. 347.

[80]See passage quoted in Eden'sHistory, i. 347.

[81]Thomas Firmin (1632-1677), a philanthropist, whose Socinianism did not exclude him from the friendship of such liberal bishops as Tillotson and Fowler, started a workhouse in 1676.

[81]Thomas Firmin (1632-1677), a philanthropist, whose Socinianism did not exclude him from the friendship of such liberal bishops as Tillotson and Fowler, started a workhouse in 1676.

[82]Nicholls (1898), ii. 14.

[82]Nicholls (1898), ii. 14.

[83]Ibid.(1898), ii. 123.

[83]Ibid.(1898), ii. 123.

[84]Report, p. 67.

[84]Report, p. 67.

[85]William Hay, for example, carried resolutions in the House of Commons in 1735, but failed to carry a bill which had this object. See Eden'sHistory, i. 396. Cooper in 1763 proposed to make the hundred the unit.—Nicholls'sHistory, i. 58. Fielding proposes a similar change in London. Dean Tucker speaks of the evil of the limited area in hisManifold Causes of the Increase of the Poor(1760).

[85]William Hay, for example, carried resolutions in the House of Commons in 1735, but failed to carry a bill which had this object. See Eden'sHistory, i. 396. Cooper in 1763 proposed to make the hundred the unit.—Nicholls'sHistory, i. 58. Fielding proposes a similar change in London. Dean Tucker speaks of the evil of the limited area in hisManifold Causes of the Increase of the Poor(1760).

[86]Nicholls, ii. 88.

[86]Nicholls, ii. 88.

[87]Parl. Hist.xxxii. 710.

[87]Parl. Hist.xxxii. 710.

[88]A full abstract is given in EdensHistory, iii. ccclxiii. etc.

[88]A full abstract is given in EdensHistory, iii. ccclxiii. etc.

[89]Bentham observes (Works, viii. 448) that the cow will require the three acres to keep it.

[89]Bentham observes (Works, viii. 448) that the cow will require the three acres to keep it.

[90]Cobbett'sPolitical Works, vi. 64

[90]Cobbett'sPolitical Works, vi. 64

[91]I need only note here that the first edition of Malthus'sEssayappeared in 1798, the year after Eden's publication.

[91]I need only note here that the first edition of Malthus'sEssayappeared in 1798, the year after Eden's publication.

[92]Eden'sHistory, i. 583.

[92]Eden'sHistory, i. 583.

[93]Ibid.i. 587.

[93]Ibid.i. 587.

[94]Maseres, an excellent Whig, a good mathematician, and a respected lawyer, is perhaps best known at present from his portrait in Charles Lamb'sOld Benchers.

[94]Maseres, an excellent Whig, a good mathematician, and a respected lawyer, is perhaps best known at present from his portrait in Charles Lamb'sOld Benchers.

[95]It maybe noticed as an anticipation of modern schemes that in 1792 Paine proposed a system of 'old age pensions,' for which the necessary funds were to be easily obtained when universal peace had abolished all military charges. SeeState Trials, xxv. 175.

[95]It maybe noticed as an anticipation of modern schemes that in 1792 Paine proposed a system of 'old age pensions,' for which the necessary funds were to be easily obtained when universal peace had abolished all military charges. SeeState Trials, xxv. 175.

II.THE POLICE

The system of 'self-government' showed its weak side in this direction. It meant that an important function was intrusted to small bodies, quite incompetent of acting upon general principles, and perfectly capable of petty jobbing, when unrestrained by any effective supervision. In another direction the same tendency was even more strikingly illustrated. Municipal institutions were almost at their lowest point of decay. Manchester and Birmingham were two of the largest and most rapidly growing towns. By the end of the century Manchester had a population of 90,000 and Birmingham of 70,000. Both were ruled, as far as they were ruled, by the remnants of old manorial institutions. Aikin[96]observes that 'Manchester (in 1795) remains an open town; destitute (probably to its advantage) of a corporation, and unrepresented in parliament.' It was governed by a 'boroughreeve' and two constables elected annually at the court-leet. William Hutton, the quaint historian of Birmingham, tells us in 1783 that the town was still legally a village, with a high and low bailiff, a 'high and low taster,' two 'affeerers,' and two 'leather-sealers,' In 1752 it had been provided with a 'court of requests' for the recovery of small debts, and in 1769 with a body of commissioners to provide for lighting the town. Thiswas the system by which, with some modifications, Birmingham was governed till after the Reform Bill.[97]Hutton boasts[98]that no town was better governed or had fewer officers. 'A town without a charter,' he says, 'is a town without a shackle.' Perhaps he changed his opinions when his warehouses were burnt in 1791, and the town was at the mercy of the mob till a regiment of 'light horse' could be called in. Aikin and Hutton, however, reflect the general opinion at a time when the town corporations had become close and corrupt bodies, and were chiefly 'shackles' upon the energy of active members of the community. I must leave the explanation of this decay to historians. I will only observe that what would need explanation would seem to be rather the absence than the presence of corruption. The English borough was not stimulated by any pressure from a central government; nor was it a semi-independent body in which every citizen had the strongest motives for combining to support its independence against neighbouring towns or invading nobles. The lower classes were ignorant, and probably would be rather hostile than favourable to any such modest interference with dirt and disorder as would commend themselves to the officials. Naturally, power was left to the little cliques of prosperous tradesmen, who formed close corporations, and spent the revenues upon feasts or squandered them by corrupt practices. Here, as in the poor-law, the insufficiency of the administrative body suggests to contemporaries, not its reform, but its superfluity.

The most striking account of some of the naturalresults is in Colquhoun's[99]Treatise on the Police of the Metropolis. Patrick Colquhoun (1745-1820), an energetic Scot, was born at Dumbarton in 1745, had been in business at Glasgow, where he was provost in 1782 and 1783, and in 1789 settled in London. In 1792 he obtained through Dundas an appointment to one of the new police magistracies created by an act of that year. He took an active part in many schemes of social reform; and his book gives an account of the investigations by which his schemes were suggested and justified. It must be said, however, parenthetically, that his statistics scarcely challenge implicit confidence. Like Sinclair and Eden, he saw the importance of obtaining facts and figures, but his statements are suspiciously precise and elaborate.[100]The broad facts are clear enough.

London was, he says, three miles broad and twenty-five in circumference. The population in 1801 was 641,000. It was the largest town, and apparently the most chaotic collection of dwellings in the civilised world. There were, as Colquhoun asserts[101]in an often-quoted passage, 20,000 people in it, who got up every morning without knowing how they would get through the day. There were 5000 public-houses, and 50,000 women supported, wholly or partly, by prostitution. The revenues raised by crime amounted, as he calculates, to an annual sum of, £2,000,000. There were whole classes of professional thieves, more or less organised ingangs, which acted in support of each other. There were gangs on the river, who boarded ships at night, or lay in wait round the warehouses. The government dockyards were systematically plundered, and the same article often sold four times over to the officials. The absence of patrols gave ample chance to the highwaymen then peculiar to England. Their careers, commemorated in theNewgate Calendar, had a certain flavour of Robin Hood romance, and their ranks were recruited from dissipated apprentices and tradesmen in difficulty. The fields round London were so constantly plundered that the rent was materially lowered. Half the hackney coachmen, he says,[102]were in league with thieves. The number of receiving houses for stolen goods had increased in twenty years from 300 to 3000.[103]Coining was a flourishing trade, and according to Colquhoun employed several thousand persons.[104]Gambling had taken a fresh start about 1777 and 1778[105]; and the keepers of tables had always money enough at command to make convictions almost impossible. French refugees at the revolution had introducedrouge et noir; and Colquhoun estimates the sums yearly lost in gambling-houses at over £7,000,000. The gamblers might perhaps appeal not only to the practices of their betters in the days of Fox, but to the public lotteries. Colquhoun had various correspondents, who do not venture to propose the abolition of a system which sanctioned the practice, but who hope to diminish the facility for supplementary betting on the results of the official drawing.

The war had tended to increase the number of looseand desperate marauders who swarmed in the vast labyrinth of London streets. When we consider the nature of the police by which these evils were to be checked, and the criminal law which they administered, the wonder is less that there were sometimes desperate riots (as in 1780) than that London should have been ever able to resist a mob. Colquhoun, though a patriotic Briton, has to admit that the French despots had at last created an efficient police. The emperor, JosephII., he says, inquired for an Austrian criminal supposed to have escaped to Paris. You will find him, replied the head of the French police, at No. 93 of such a street in Vienna on the second-floor room looking upon such a church; and there he was. In England a criminal could hide himself in a herd of his like, occasionally disturbed by the inroad of a 'Bow Street runner,' the emissary of the 'trading justices,' formerly represented by the two Fieldings. An act of 1792 created seven new offices, to one of which Colquhoun had been appointed. They had one hundred and eighty-nine paid officers under them. There were also about one thousand constables. These were small tradesmen or artisans upon whom the duty was imposed without remuneration for a year by their parish, that is, by one of seventy independent bodies. A 'Tyburn ticket,' given in reward for obtaining the conviction of a criminal exempted a man from the discharge of such offices, and could be bought for from £15 to £25. There were also two thousand watchmen receiving from 8½d. up to 2s. a night. These were the true successors of Dogberry; often infirm or aged persons appointed to keep them out of the workhouse.The management of this distracted force thus depended upon a miscellaneous set of bodies; the paid magistrates, the officials of the city, the justices of the peace for Middlesex, and the seventy independent parishes.

The law was as defective as the administration. Colquhoun represents the philanthropic impulse of the day, and notices[106]that in 1787 JosephII.had abolished capital punishment. His chief authority for more merciful methods is Beccaria; and it is worth remarking, for reasons which will appear hereafter, that he does not in this connection refer to Bentham, although he speaks enthusiastically[107]of Bentham's model prison, the Panopticon. Colquhoun shows how strangely the severity of the law was combined with its extreme capaciousness. He quotes Bacon[108]for the statement that the law was a 'heterogeneous mass concocted too often on the spur of the moment,' and gives sufficient proofs of its truth. He desires, for example, a law to punish receivers of stolen goods, and says that there were excellent laws in existence. Unfortunately one law applied exclusively to the case of pewter-pots, and another exclusively to the precious metals; neither could be used as against receivers of horses or bank notes.[109]So a man indicted under an act against stealing from ships on navigable rivers escaped, because the barge from which he stole happened to be aground. Gangs could afford to corrupt witnesses or to pay knavish lawyers skilled in applying these vagaries of legislation. Juries also disliked convicting when the penalty for coining sixpence was the same as the penalty for killing a mother. It followed, as he shows by statistics, that half the persons committed fortrial escaped by petty chicanery or corruption, or the reluctance of juries to convict for capital offences. Only about one-fifth of the capital sentences were executed; and many were pardoned on condition of enlisting to improve the morals of the army. The criminals, who were neither hanged nor allowed to escape, were sent to prisons, which were schools of vice. After the independence of the American colonies, the system of transportation to Australia had begun (in 1787); but the expense was enormous, and prisoners were huddled together in the hulks at Woolwich and Portsmouth, which had been used as a temporary expedient. Thence they were constantly discharged, to return to their old practices. A man, says Colquhoun,[110]would deserve a statue who should carry out a plan for helping discharged prisoners. To meet these evils, Colquhoun proposes various remedies, such as a metropolitan police, a public prosecutor, or even a codification or revision of the Criminal Code, which he sees is likely to be delayed. He also suggested, in a pamphlet of 1799, a kind of charity organisation society to prevent the waste of funds. Many other pamphlets of similar tendencies show his active zeal in promoting various reforms. Colquhoun was in close correspondence with Bentham from the year 1798,[111]and Bentham helped him by drawing the Thames Police Act, passed in 1800, to give effect to some of the suggestions in theTreatise.[112]

Another set of abuses has a special connection with Bentham's activity. Bentham had been led in 1778 to attend to the prison question by reading Howard's book onPrisons; and he refers to the 'venerable friendwho had lived an apostle and died a martyr.'[113]The career of John Howard (1726-1790) is familiar. The son of a London tradesman, he had inherited an estate in Bedfordshire. There he erected model cottages and village schools; and, on becoming sheriff of the county in 1773, was led to attend to abuses in the prisons. Two acts of parliament were passed in 1774 to remedy some of the evils exposed, and he pursued the inquiry at home and abroad. His results are given in hisState of the Prisons in England and Wales(1779, fourth edition, 1792), and hisAccount of the Principal Lazarettos in Europe(1789). The prisoners, he says, had little food, sometimes a penny loaf a day, and sometimes nothing; no water, no fresh air, no sewers, and no bedding. The stench was appalling, and gaol fever killed more than died on the gallows. Debtors and felons, men, women and children, were huddled together; often with lunatics, who were shown by the gaolers for money. 'Garnish' was extorted; the gaolers kept drinking-taps; gambling flourished: and prisoners were often cruelly ironed, and kept for long periods before trial. At Hull the assizes had only been held once in seven years, and afterwards once in three. It is a comfort to find that the whole number of prisoners in England and Wales amounted, in 1780, to about 4400, 2078 of whom were debtors, 798 felons, and 917 petty offenders. An act passed in 1779 provided for the erection of two penitentiaries. Howard was to be a supervisor. The failure to carry out this act led, as we shall see, to one of Bentham's most characteristic undertakings. One peculiarity must be noted.Howard found prisons on the continent where the treatment was bad and torture still occasionally practised; but he nowhere found things so bad as in England. In Holland the prisons were so neat and clean as to make it difficult to believe that they were prisons: and they were used as models for the legislation of 1779. One cause of this unenviable distinction of English prisons had been indicated by an earlier investigation. General Oglethorpe (1696-1785) had been started in his philanthropic career by obtaining a committee of the House of Commons in 1729 to inquire into the state of the gaols. The foundation of the colony of Georgia as an outlet for the population was one result of the inquiry. It led, in the first place, however, to a trial of persons accused of atrocious cruelties at the Fleet prison.[114]The trial was abortive. It appeared in the course of the proceedings that the Fleet prison was a 'freehold,' A patent for rebuilding it had been granted to Sir Jeremy Whichcot under CharlesII., and had been sold to one Higgins, who resold it to other persons for £5000. The proprietors made their investment pay by cruel ill-treatment of the prisoners, oppressing the poor and letting off parts of the prison to dealers in drink. This was the general plan in the prisons examined by Howard, and helps to account for the gross abuses. It is one more application of the general system. As the patron was owner of a living, and the officer of his commission, the keeper of a prison was owner of his establishment. The paralysis of administration which prevailed throughout the country made it natural to farm out paupers to the master of a workhouse, and prisoners to the proprietor of a gaol.The state of prisoners may be inferred not only from Howard's authentic record but from the fictions of Fielding, Smollett and Goldsmith; and the last echoes of the same complaints may be found inPickwickandLittle Dorrit. The Marshalsea described in the last was also a proprietary concern. We shall hereafter see how Bentham proposed to treat the evils revealed by Oglethorpe and Howard.


Back to IndexNext